Japan Railway & Transport Review No. 51 (p6-p11)
Feature: Railways and The Environment(part 3) Rail Transport and Environmental Costs — Policy and Research in Europe Chris Nash Markus Maibach |
![]() |
Introduction |
Rail transport is seen as being of growing importance in
Europe and elsewhere due to its lower environmental impact
than other transport modes. Previously, the advantage of
rail was seen in terms of noise, visual and local air pollution.
While all these factors are still important, energy consumption
and greenhouse-gas emissions have become the main
concerns. |
Valuation of Environmental Externalities |
In an efficient market economy, prices indicate the costs
of alternative goods and services. Consumers can choose
whether particular goods and services are worth the cost, or
whether they prefer cheaper alternatives. In turn, companies
will decide whether to invest in productive capacity on the
basis of a comparison between the revenue they earn from
the facilities and the cost of providing them. |
Photo: Mitigating climate change is one of the most important challenges for the transport sector |
Values of Environmental Externalities by Mode |
Many studies have been undertaken of environmental costs
of transport in Europe, sponsored either by the European
Commission or individual member countries. Evidence on
social cost estimation has recently been synthesized in the
form of a EU handbook published by the IMPACT project. |
Policy Uses of Environmental Valuations |
There are three main ways in which environmental values
are used in Europe—regulation, pricing, and investment
appraisal. Regulation is used in a number of contexts. For example, there are noise and air pollution standards that all new road vehicles in Europe must meet, and there is debate on whether to extend this to regulation of the average greenhouse-gas emissions of new cars. There are requirements about noise levels of aircraft and of railway rolling stock. Once the value of the environmental externality is known, the appropriate level of these standards may be determined by comparing the benefits with the costs, taking care to include any indirect effects—for example, energy consumption standards that reduce the cost of motoring may lead to additional travel, offsetting some benefits. Pricing is used to reflect the real costs of different transport modes, and may impact in a number of ways: how many motorized trips to make, where to go, what mode of transport to use, what type of vehicle if the choice is road, etc. For this reason, pricing has major advantages over regulation; for example pricing may lead someone travelling short distances in a rural area to choose a low-cost but more-polluting car, but would give someone covering long distances in urban areas where the cost of emissions is much higher a much greater incentive to buy a low-emission car. Generally, environmental externalities are produced by use of transport infrastructure, and vary with the type of vehicle, location, and time of day. Thus, ideally they must be incorporated into an infrastructure charge. (The obvious exception is the effects of global warming, which do not vary with where and when the carbon is emitted, so a fuel tax that is proportional to the carbon content of the fuel is an ideal internalization instrument.) For roads, the ideal would be universal electronic road pricing; in its absence, second-best methods such as simple kilometer-based charges (differentiated according to vehicle categories considering environmental performance), fuel tax, and annual licence duty have to be used. For rail in Europe, there is now a requirement that explicit charges are levied for use of infrastructure. This has occurred because of the policy of opening-up infrastructure to new entrants. Some countries differentiate these charges by type of vehicle according to the noise level produced, and one or two countries charge for air pollution and/or global warming through tax on diesel fuel. For air and water transport, the choice is between adding such charges to port or airport charges, or to air traffic control or specific fees for the use of coastal waters. Whilst some countries do differentiate airport landing charges according to noise nuisance, this is generally used to recover the cost of noise countermeasures rather than to price the noise nuisance itself; Sweden is unique in charging fees for the use of coastal waters to reflect air pollution costs. Appraisal refers mainly to investment projects but may also be applied to broader policy questions. The point here is to allow for the impact of new rail, road or (air) port infrastructure, not just on the mode in question but also on other modes. Consequently, for example, the environmental externalities produced by a new railway line will be at least partly offset by reduced externalities from other modes. However, it must be remembered that when new railway infrastructure is provided, not all the railway trips using it would otherwise have used road or air. In the UK, it is estimated that about half of the additional rail travel generated by improved inter-city rail services would otherwise have used car, with a load factor of around 1.8 per vehicle, so that on average an additional rail passenger-km removes about 0.25% of a carkm from the roads. The EU now includes 27 countries in western and central Europe; the main non-members, such as Switzerland and Norway, largely follow its lead. Since the mid 1990s, EU policy has been to internalize externalities in transport prices, but progress in implementing this through EU Directives has been slow. (EU Directives must be agreed by the European Parliament and Council of Ministers, and then must be implemented by all member countries). The EU only legislates on issues affecting competition between and integration of its members, so in the transport field it is concerned with commercial traffic, particularly international, rather than private cars. In the rail sector, marginal social cost is taken as the basis for track access charges (EU Directive 2001/14/EC). Charges may be differentiated with respect to environmental impacts, but this must not add to the average level of charges, unless environmental costs are also reflected in charges for other modes. Mark-ups on marginal social cost are permitted where necessary in order to finance particular schemes or rail infrastructure in general when the government does not provide sufficient funding for the applied pure marginal social cost pricing. In the case of electricity for rail traction, the costs of global warming are internalized to a degree by inclusion of electricity generation in the European emissions trading scheme; there are proposals to extend this approach to air transport and possibly to water. Otherwise, there are currently no proposals for European legislation to internalize the costs of environmental externalities for the air and water transport modes. For the road sector, following EU Directive 2006/38/EC on road charges (amending 1999/62/EC), the EU allows introduction of tolls on HGVs on all roads. Differentiation is possible according to congestion and accident costs and the environmental performance of vehicles, indicated by the EURO category of HGV. This differentiation must be designed so that the total revenues from tolls do not exceed the total allocated infrastructure costs, except that a surcharge of up to 25%—which can be used to fund alternative modes of transport—is permitted in environmentally sensitive areas, such as the Alps. Switzerland (a non-EU country) was the first to introduce a kilometer-based charge for HGVs; Germany and Austria have followed suit and many more countries are considering doing so. The European Parliament has argued strongly that the overall level of charges should reflect levels of externalities. Further proposals to amend the above Directive to allow full charging of external costs of congestion, noise and air pollution, with any additional revenue to be used for improving the environmental performance of the transport system, were brought forward by the European Commission in July 2008. (Costs of climate change are thought to be best internalized through fuel tax, and external accident costs through improved methods of insurance.) Charging for private cars is regarded as a matter for individual member states. With respect to assessment approaches for infrastructure, the development of the Trans-European Networks is the most important issue for the European Commission, because it is the only transport infrastructure with explicit European funding, although there is greater funding of transport from structural and cohesion funds designed to benefit poorer and peripheral countries. At the EU level, methodological baselines have been developed, especially for evaluation of infrastructure projects in Eastern Europe (e.g. the TINA programme). The results of the HEATCO European project have—for the first time—harmonized guidelines for cost benefit analysis (CBA) in transport at the European level. These guidelines will set the standard for the assessment of future transport projects in Europe. However, most countries still have their own guidelines concerning CBA in transport including social costs: e.g. the Netherlands (Overzicht Effecten Infrastuctuur, OEI), United Kingdom (New Approach to Appraisal, NATA), Austria (Strategische Prufung im Verkehrsbereich, SP-V), Finland (Guidelines for the Assessment of Transport Infrastructure Projects in Finland), and Germany (Bundesverkehrswegeplan). |
Conclusion |
Typically, rail is much less environmentally polluting than other transport modes, and this must be reflected in regulation, pricing, and investment appraisal. The advantage of rail varies greatly with circumstances, being much greater for a heavily loaded urban electric train using electricity generated from renewable resources than for a lightly loaded rural diesel train. Pricing will automatically give the correct incentives provided it is sophisticated enough to reflect such differences; regulation and appraisal must also take differences into account for rail to play its optimum role in tackling environmental problems. |
Chris Nash Professor Chris Nash is Professor of Transport Economics in the Institute for Transport Studies, University of Leeds (ITS), which is one of the leading transport research groups in Great Britain. He has acted as expert advisor to many groups, including the High Level Group on Transport Infrastructure Charges of the EC, the Railways group of ECMT, and the Transport and European Union Select Committees of the British Parliament. His recent work includes coordinating the DGTREN funded GRACE project on measuring the marginal social cost of use of transport infrastructure, and—as part of the IMPRINT-NET project—leading Europe-wide expert groups on road and rail infrastructure charges and the use of funds from road pricing. |
Markus Maibach Mr Markus Maibach is currently a Transport Policy Adviser, Manager, and Partner of INFRAS (Consulting, Policy Analysis, Research). He joined INFRAS in 1987. From 1988 to 1989, he conducted transport economics surveys for projects in Myanmar and Nepal. Since 1990, he has been a project manager in the area of transport with further specializations in energy/environment, evaluation of large projects, and sustainable development. He earned a Master’s degree in economics and economic geography at the University of Zurich in 1984. |